In his essay
‘The Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren’ Keynes envisaged a future
that would afford people the possibility to ‘live wisely and agreeably and
well.’ At this stage, he wrote ‘I see us free, therefore, to return to some of
the most sure and certain principles of religion and traditional virtue -- that
avarice is a vice, that the exaction of usury is a misdemeanour...’
The big
question is why that time of well-being is not possible now. What cause
withholds us to achieve it? Keynes answers the question while guarding us
against the perils of moving towards that stage too enthusiastically. ‘Beware!’
he said, after his vision of the millennium ‘The time for all this is not yet.
For at least another hundred years, we must pretend to ourselves and to everyone
that fair is foul and foul is fair, for foul is useful and fair is not. Avarice
and usury and precaution must be our gods for a little longer still. For only
they can lead us out of the tunnel of economic necessity into daylight.’
So, ‘foul’ is
useful. ‘Economic necessity’ makes it so. What economic necessity? To whom is
this foul useful? Mine eyes behold the minority affluent of my land living
‘happily ever after’ with their merry-making and with their easy access to the
huge funds the country borrows for the ‘economic necessity’ of affording these
gods and goddesses their never ending binge. And mine eyes behold the rest of
the living -- the ordinary majority -- struggling and striving and labouring to
eke out a precarious subsistence.
Yea, yea,
there’s this wee, ‘growing’ middle-class as well, the youth of which have that
fine ornament the gods call talent -- talent which the youth spend more on vain
efforts to emulate them gods rather than on their own productivity and
development. Yet, in these youth there’s a reason for the dear country to hope.
But the ‘foul’ is rarely useful to them in a land where not more than 2.5% of
the revenue expenditure is spent on education and where a talented young person
often has to figure out the grand puzzle: which honest trade, apart from
speculation of course, can afford him or her a profit high enough to pay for the
heavy interest on a loan of just three lac rupees from YIPS that is supposed to
be given to the talented youth who do not have enough capital already to pledge
as collateral for a true share of the borrowed funds our rulers regard national
wealth?
The question
thus remains: to whom is this ‘foul’ useful? and what ‘economic necessity’
justifies it? Time has now clearly shown that the ‘invisible-hand’ has rarely
been benevolent to the have-nots, and that the celebrated ‘equilibrium’ it
causes has no relation as such with their ‘wants’ and needs, as it may result at
a level much below the needs of individuals; for demand in economics is not
‘wants’, still less ‘needs’. Demand is money - votes, which determine what is to
be produced, how much is to be produced and for whom it is to be produced. With
this magic wand, the affluent can cause such patterns of production and
distribution as churn out superfluous luxuries, while the majority, containing
millions of potential, average innovators, entrepreneurs, thinkers and skilled
works -- essential for pervasive economic development -- and a number of
potential Einsteins, Edisons and Lee Lacoccas -- essential for breakthroughs --
do not even get the share of resources to come out of the vicious trap of
poverty which confines their potential to the most menial of chores for the rest
of their lives. This is not only morally despicable but very bad economics as
well, for there is no factor of production more important -- economically and
socially -- than human beings. As Sismondi (1773-1842) asserted, we must be
concerned with not only how big the stock of wealth is but also with ‘For Whom?’
it is being piled. ‘No nation’ he said ‘can be considered as prosperous, if the
condition of the poor, who form a part of it, is not secure....’ -- in our case,
that of the majority. The ability of a nation to produce wealth depends not on
the self-interest of a few individuals, but on a culture conducive to the
production of wealth. As List (1789-1846) put it ‘The prosperity of a nation is
great, not in proportion to the accumulation of wealth, but in proportion to the
development of productive forces.’ Among these ‘productive forces’ are a
required variety of natural resources, science and technology, appropriate laws,
law and order, a congenial environment for industry, commerce and services, a
sense of proportion, and, above all, moral values. Says George Soule:
Again and
again, it has been discovered that a nation cannot much benefit merely by
attracting large foreign loans and putting up highly mechanised factories,
unless more elementary cultural and material advances have created the readiness
to make good use of these facilities. Education, health, desire for improvement,
reasonably honest and orderly government, a harmonious interrelationship among
agriculture, manufacture, commerce, and good transportation, are all found to be
necessary....1
Culture is
created by people, whose behaviour is greatly influenced by the structure of the
society and the pervailing values. A thing is worth as much as people think it
is worth. If the people with the magic wand of demand think cottage industry is
important and divert their resources towards it, cottage industry will become
important. If they think construction of beautiful government buildings is more
important and direct their money-votes towards it, that construction will become
more important. The rigmarole theory of ‘the invisible-hand’ being stimulated by
economic activity to benefit everyone often fails when disparity of income and
wealth is so great as it is in our society. Even Keynes conceded that wide
disparity in the distribution of income has the tendency to increase saving and
restrict investment because the majority poor do not have the ability to
generate enough demand to stimulate investment out of the attempted saving by
the affluent.
The key word
then is values. What is more important to those who are important in society?
Most of Western economics has concerned itself with material welfare of man in
the hope that his material welfare will lead to prosperity and justice and
compassion in society. This topsy-turvy premise has justified the hedonism of
the ‘economic man’ to the extent such justification was useful to the prosperous
class. Reality is the other way round. It is when the ethos of a society
consists in nobler values as justice and compassion, hardwork and industry, and
entrepreneurship and co-operation that material welfare is ensured to the
majority of its members. Where material progress has been made in disregard or
negation of nobler values, such progress has often, if not always, been the
outcome of exploitation of man by man.
The problem
though is that the assumption of ‘economic man model’ is not wrong per se. Each
one of us does want material benefit for his or her ownself and wants to take
such decisions as would lead to his or her material prosperity. Preservation of
values, on the other hand, often requires sacrifice of material benefit. Sure,
we all love to pay lip-service to the idea of being nice and all that, but, deep
down, hardly anyone wants to be ‘the sucker left holding the bag’2, especially
when no reward of any kind is anywhere in sight, not even in the longer-run.
Sure enough, it is part of human nature to be altruistic also. But does that
aspect of human personality make economic sense, especially when we are talking
about sacrifice in the real sense of the word, which sacrifice is essential for
concrete and lasting change in society, not about paternalistic, condescending
charity which cons conscience into accepting as desirable much less than what is
actually required? The answer lies in that realm of human life which Western
economics has unsuccessfully tried to ignore: religion. The West began its age
of ‘Enlightenment’ with the virtual abandonment of belief in God and with its
substitution by belief in Nature. Even most of those who still held on to
religion in one way or the other believed that God brought His will to pass
through nature and its laws.
The
philosophers of Enlightenment insinuated that misery of man was the result of
disobeying ‘natural laws’. Nature now was the ‘Father’ -- impersonal, yet
systematic and benevolent. They talked about the results of ‘deviations’ from
the norms of some imaginary society in the distant past when everybody was happy
because nothing ‘un-natural’ existed. As George Soule has put it ‘In this
disguised form they revived, without being conscious that they were doing it,
the legend of the Garden of Eden as the prototype of a new earthly paradise they
were intent on creating.’ But we know that life is rarely perfect. To sacrifice
material benefit in the true sense of the word just for the preservation of
values especially when no reasonable reward is in sight, not even in the
longer-run, is a decision that makes economic sense only if you are certain that
in such persecution ‘great is your reward in heaven’. That kind of reward can
provide Veblen’s3 ‘leisure class’ and ‘captains of industry’ with the
purposiveness they need to replace the ‘virtues’ of ‘ferocity, self-seeking,
clannishness, disingenousness, and a free resort to force and fraud’ with
genuine altruism where it is most needed.
Therefore,
religion, especially Islam, gives an absolutely different direction to life than
the one charted out by Western ‘Enlightenment’. Indeed, in Islam, the very
purpose of a person’s life is different: it is servitude to God4. With this
purpose, the whole perspective changes. Life becomes a trial rather than a
reward or punishment. ‘Freedom’ does not remain a privilege that is unrestrained
by anything but ‘nature’ -- which itself can be cruel as well as kind -- or a
privilege that is considered justified in taking no account of ethical
constraints imposed by reason and Divine revelation. Freedom becomes a
responsibility.
All the
directives and injunctions of Islam -- whether they relate to a person’s
economic activity or to other social and individual dealings -- have one basic
aim: the ‘purification of a person’s soul’5 to enable him or her to be a true
servant and slave of God.
Such people as
have no desire or inclination to be God’s servants can easily find justification
in concepts as the ‘invisible-hand’ for their deviation, which makes them
captives of their base desires. To such people, the underlying wisdom of the
laws of God can rarely be explained. But to the servants and slaves of God, a
lot can be said. And if those who have authority and power among men -- the
affluent and the elite -- become men of God rather than becoming false gods
themselves, a lot can be done. As Robert Owen (1771-1858) said:
Any general
character, from the best to the worst, from the most ignorant to the most
enlightened, may be given to any community, even to the world at large, by the
application of proper means; which means to a great extent are under the control
of those who have influence in the affairs of men.
Assuming --
for the sake of argument only -- that those in authority in our dear country are
men of God, this unworthy scribe would to like say a few things to the gods....
er, sorry, to the men of God who live on the Mount Olympus in Islamabad and who
serve the rest of the country from up there.
In the
following lines are some assertions regarding Islam and economics followed by
some suggestions for economic policy making. Regarding Islam, it must be said at
the outset that where any unequivocal directive or injunction exists in the
Qur’ān or the Sunnah, the question of ijtihād does not arise. The only task for
a scholar of Islam is to interpret the directives and injunctions in relation to
their context. For example, since Ribā has been prohibited in the Qur’ān, what
Ribā means is a question which must be looked into vis-a-vis the context and the
language of the Qur’ān. While dealing with the question of the meaning of Ribā,
the line of argument which takes into account factors extraneous to the Qur’ān
and, on that basis, regards practicable solutions which do not fit into the
context of the relevant verses of the Qur’ān as the true expression of the
meaning of the book does no justice to this Divine source of guidance. Only that
meaning can be accepted as correct which truly emanates from the language and
the context of the relevant verses in the Qur’ān. The question of viability
should be tackled thereafter6. Ijtihād, or intellectual reasoning, is for
matters not touched upon by the original sources of Divine guidance. A book is
not interpreted by intellectual reasoning which is used to ‘rationalise’ it, but
by using the principles of linguistics to arrive at the true meaning of its
contents. Therefore, if one finds those contents unreasonable or impracticable,
one should have the intellectual courage to say so. To put extraneous solutions
into the context of a book to ‘rationalise’ it is downright intellectual
dishonesty.
In the
following lines, assertions related to Islam are based on the interpretation of
the Qur’ān and the Sunnah and on a general understanding of Islam and its
spirit. These assertions should therefore be repugned or accepted on same bases
rather than on the basis of extraneous factors related to the question of
viability. Quite often what is practical and useful seems impracticable because
the overall environment necessary for it does not exist. In such cases, it is
not wise to do away with the ideal itself. ‘Ideals’ as a Frenchman has put it
‘are often like stars. You can’t always reach them, but you can use them to
chart out your course.’ If you change the ideal on the grounds that you can’t
reach it all at once, then you’ll change the direction altogether; then you’ll
never get there. If it is difficult, or even impossible, to be thoroughly honest
in our society, it does not mean that our ideal should be abolishing only 50% or
60% of the existing corruption. We have to keep on trying to move gradually
towards the ideal.
However, all
the other assertions, related to economics and the suggestions, that follow are
subject to open debate vis-a-vis their viability. But even here, it must be
remembered that quite often the solution to unresolved problems lies in the
radical vision of a path finder who has the sagacity and the courage to go
beyond existing perimeters. Any such person, whose vision is based on serious
academic work rather than on just whims, deserves a fair audience, if nothing
else.
Now, for the
assertions:
I.
Regarding Islam
1. Islam has
not given any economic system. In fact, it has not given any social system. A
system is essentially a set or assemblage of interconnected and interdependent
things that form a complex unity7. If Islam had given social systems in that
sense it would have been obsolete long ago. It has however given certain
universal ethical principles for the purification of human soul.
2. In the
case of vices which have pervaded society to the extent that their eradication
in one stroke can only cause greater disruption and evil than the one which is
sought to be rooted out, Islam has always had a gradual approach towards
implementation (for example, its gradual prohibition of intoxicants during the
Prophet’s time -- sws)
3. Islam does
not take away the freedom of an individual to own and use wealth. Only in
exceptional cases, where the chances of exploitation are great, does it take
away the right to ‘use’ wealth8. Also, it acknowledges the fact that there are
natural differences among humans in relation to their abilities, circumstances
and wealth. These differences create a harmonious society if each individual is
given a fair and just opportunity to utilise his or her potential. Islam
restrains the freedom of an individual seeking his or her material benefit only
to the extent that there is no exploitation and that the collective and personal
activities of an individual do not hinder his or her soul’s purification, which
purification is essential for enabling an individual to become a true servant of
God. Purification of human soul is the underlying spirit of injuctions as the
prohibition of Ribā and of directives as the implementation of Zakāh.
II Regarding
economics
1. There is
no viable basis for institutional credit creation -- the primary function of
banks -- apart from interest. If there had been, someone would have found it by
now. The Jews tried it, the Christians tried it, the Muslims tried it9. All
failed. It’s time we started looking for an alternative solution rather than
wasting further efforts on looking for alternatives to interest as a basis for
institutional credit creation. Perhaps, the solution lies in looking for a
banking-free economy rather than in looking for an interest-free banking system.
A radical idea perhaps, but one that needs looking into, especially since
preserving the existing structure of banking is not a Divine commandment.
2. Since, as
Paul Samuelson has put it ‘A thing is worth what people think it is worth’10,
values can have the profoundest economic impact. In the promotion and
preservation of any value, the affluent and the elite who are at the helm of
affairs have a great role to play. It is not only through laws but also through
personal example that values are inculcated. That is why it used to be a
convention in true Islamic societies that a ruler’s standard of living never
went above that of an average person.
3. An
economic system does not exist in isolation. Any successful economic guideline
requires certain accompanying factors in the political, legal, social and
cultural set-ups shaping the economy11.
III.
Recommendations
The economy
should be re-structured on the bases of a just distribution of wealth and
self-reliance in such a manner that gradually the government is left with no
need to impose any tax on its citizens others than Zakāh12.
Details of
this suggestion, which is based on the ideas of Javed Ahmad Ghamidi13, are
presented by Shehzad Saleem in the next editorial. While considering these
suggestions in relation to budget making, the following points must also be
considered:
1. Usually,
policy makers in our country think of only one way of reducing the gap between
revenue and expenditure: increasing the revenue -- which is generally done
through additional borrowing or increased taxation or both. Yet, another way has
always been there: reducing the expenditure -- the wrong kind of expenditure.
Expenditure which eats up the stock of capital goods more quickly than it adds
to it or leads to such patterns of production and distribution as make the rich
richer at the cost of the development of the rest certainly needs to be
curtailed. Changing the structure of expenditure requires courage, commitment
and sagacity. But it can be done.
At the
moment, the greatest curse our nation is facing is debt-servicing. Domestic debt
servicing alone was Rs. 113 billion last year in the revenue account of the
federal budget. If the government, by taking the masses into confidence, musters
up enough political support to get the majority vote on this one14, it can
declare a moratorium on the payment of domestic debt on the basis of the
Qur’ānic verse which urges a lender to extend the time of ease for a borrower in
straitened circumstances15. All interest payment on domestic debt can
immediately be stopped on the grounds of interest being un-Islamic. The current
value of debt may be linked to gold and re-payment assured on that basis so that
no panic results. The facility of sale (through the Exchange) of marketable
instruments of this debt may continue. The time-period for re-payment in gold
(or value thereof) may be delayed for at least 15 years so that ample time is
available for generating income by using the saved funds for productive and
developmental enterprise. With this one stroke, the largest chunk of expenditure
can be dealt with. All other superfluous expenditures must also be curtailed or
stopped.
2. Zakāh is
usually thought of as a very narrowly-based tax. This tax, with its inherent
appeal of being an obligatory ritual of worship for a Muslim, has a very wide
base (as is explained ahead) and can be used for all collective and State
purposes. In this regard, the condition of Tamlīk imposed by some jurists, which
restricts its use to personal possession at the level of individuals who belong
to the destitute class, has no basis in the Qur’ān or Sunnah16. It is suggested
that this tax be used to the fullest extent to broaden the base of taxation,
especially by including agricultural produce in real terms.
3. Since the
government has the right to take away the right of use from incompetent owners
of wealth so that exploitation in society is checked17, it should look into the
possibility of sharing in the management of large, under-utilised tracts of
agricultural lands. Some suggestions in this regard follow in the next section.
4. The
financial system should be restructured in such a way that interest is abolished
and indigenous entrepreneurship, especially at the middle-income levels and at
the levels of cottage industry, is encouraged. (See the first suggestion in the
next section for how this restructuring may actually be done).
5. Further
foreign loans should not be taken. Efforts should be made to retire all foreign
debt in the next 15 years. Superfluous expenditure must be put to an end, the
government and its members should promote austerity by personal example, and the
more well-off segments of society should take the lead in making the dream of
full retirement of debt a reality. Had the present government been a true
leadership of the masses rather than of the affluent and of the industrial
bourgeoisie, one might even have suggested some drastic measures for the
retirement of debt, considering the gravity of the situation. These drastic
measures would have included among many others, redistribution or acquisition of
land on the basis of original ownership before the British took control from the
Muslim rulers of India and acquisition of or sharing in the management of
enterprises set up in the private sector through funds borrowed from the State
controlled banks and DFI’s. (Alternatively, a system of Khirāj could be used as
suggested in the next section for ‘less drastic’ measures).
The unhallowed
hand of this scribe presents these suggestions with full awareness that in all
probability the rulers of today will rather choose to ignore them. But since
there is hope in the younger generation, these suggestions it must present.
Perhaps, the Nawaz Sharifs and Benazir Bhuttos of the future will pay heed to
them in a time when there is no difference between making money and making
goods, when the man who makes most money is no longer one who exploits others,
stifles indigenous enterprise with his interest-based business expansion and
cut-throat competition or who, with his speculation and interest-based business
activity, creates for small investors, entrepreneurs and for the majority of
people in society problems as panics, industrial failures and unemployment.
But until
then, until darkness gives way to that daylight, it seems we have no choice but
to continue in the worship of avarice, interest18 and precaution as our gods.
________________
_________________________
|